From KALLISTE@delphi.comThu Oct 10 11:44:36 1996
Date: Wed, 09 Oct 1996 19:54:31 -0500 (EST)
From: KALLISTE@delphi.com
To: jya@pipeline.com, jqp@globaldialog.com, tenega@aol.com,
    jw-rh@ix.netcom.com, bigred@duracef.shout.net, jlavis@communique.net,
    liberty@gate.net, vikbob@halcyon.com, rwb@daka.com, cato@cato.org,
    akimery@citizen.infi.net, pwatson@utdallas.edu, garb@ix.netcom.com,
    maddog6@flex.net, edb@interport.com, wdmann@ix.netcom.com,
    germanic@netcom.com, eric@remailer.net, sandfort@crl.com,
    loboazul@icsi.net, bdolan@use.usit.net, fathom9@aol.com,
    defraud@tpi.net, L.L.Grabbe@theol.hull.ac.uk, JMcCorm215@aol.com,
    jdtabor.uncc@uncc.campus.mci.net, zns@interserv.com, tbyfield@panix.com,
    drdean@bio.win.net, rpedraza@sierra.net, kalliste@aci.net
Subject: Here Come the Zombies

		 Here Come the Zombies

		   by J. Orlin Grabbe

	Like to gamble with other people's money?  Then 
you need to start a bank.  Because your government likes 
to make bankers rich.  Deposit insurance is one way.

	Buckaroo Banker has $200,000.  He takes half of 
this--$100,000--and uses it as capital to start a bank.  He 
offers nice interest rates on deposits, and attracts $900,000 
in deposits.  So the bank now has a million dollars in 
assets.  Buckaroo takes the million dollars to Harrahs in 
Reno and bets it all on Black at the routlette table.  Also, 
at the same spin of the wheel, he bets the $100,000 he still 
has of his own money on Red.

	And why not?  Consider the advantages.  If Red 
comes up, the bank loses all one million dollars of its 
assets.  But repaying the $900,000 owed to depositors is 
the government's problem:  the government insured the 
deposits.  Meanwhile, Buckaroo's $100,000 bet on Red 
has turned into $200,000.  So he is as well off as before.

	But if Black comes up, Buckeroo loses the 
$100,000 bet on Red, but the one million dollar bet on 
Black becomes two million.  So Buckeroo pays back the 
$900,000 he owes depositors, and walks away with $1.1 
million.

	That is, due to government deposit insurance, 
Buckeroo has a fifty percent chance of ending up with the 
$200,000 he started with, and a fifty percent chance of 
increasing the $200,000 to $1.1 million.  Personally, I 
would say:  Go for it, Buckeroo!  

	Consider the recent Savings & Loan crisis in the 
United States.  The S&L industry was the product of a 
government effort to promote home ownership.  S&Ls 
were financial institutions constrained to take in short-
term deposits and invest the money in long-term 
mortgages secured by residential property.   The structure 
of an S&L, borrowing very short-term and lending very 
long-term, thus entailed a serious gamble on interest rates. 

	In the inflation of the late 1970s, market short-
term interest rates rose above locked-in, long-term 
mortgage rates. This would have, at a minimum, required 
S&Ls to pay more on their deposits than was received on 
their loans.  But the situation was even worse because 
there were regulatory ceilings on interest rates, intended 
to "protect" S&Ls from high funding costs. Ceilings 
instead threatened to prevent the S&Ls from receiving 
deposits altogether.  S&Ls paid 5 1/4 to 5 1/2 percent on 
small-denomination deposits, while market interest rates 
(and inflation) had risen to more than double that level by 
the end of the 70s.  (Three-month Treasury bills averaged 
10.04 percent in 1979 and 11.5 percent in 1980.  The 
change in the Consumer Price Index was 13.3 percent in 
1979 and 12.5 percent in 1980.)  

	So savers removed deposits from S&Ls as well as 
banks, and placed them in money market mutual funds, 
which paid market interest rates.  Money market mutual 
funds, which grew in assets from less than $10 billion to 
$188 billion between 1978 and 1981,  lent savings back to 
S&Ls and banks by purchasing from them large-
denomination certificates of deposit which were not 
subject to interest rate ceilings.  S&Ls were thus paying 
more to their marginal depositors than they were receiving 
on their portfolio of old mortgages.  The value of their 
mortgage portfolio, meanwhile, had fallen with the rise in 
interest rates.  "By 1980, before any deregulation had 
taken place, the liabilities of the S&L industry exceeded 
its assets by $110 billion.  The industry was already 
insolvent-its members owed more than they 
owned-when Congress and the Carter administration 
enacted the Depository Institutions Deregulation and 
Monetary Control Act [DIDMCA] of 1980" (Catherine 
England, "Lessons from the Savings and Loan Debacle, 
Regulation, Summer 1992).          
	
	We arrive at the crucial juncture.
	
	DIDMCA and the Garn-St. Germain Depository 
Institutions Act of 1982 (GSGDIA) gave the S&Ls a free 
call option.  DIDMCA expanded federal deposit insurance 
from $40,000 to $100,000 per account, even while it 
phased out the interest rate ceilings S&Ls could pay on 
small-denomination deposits.  (S&L deposits were 
insured by the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance 
Corporation, or FSLIC.)  GSGDIA then expanded the 
range of allowable S&L investments.  

	Now suppose you are an insolvent, or "zombie," 
thrift.  You know you are insolvent, or are heading in that 
direction, but the regulators don't know it yet-not until 
their next audit, which may be a while, because you are 
not the only institution with problems, and they have a lot 
of work on their hands.  So what you do is, first, get new 
money by offering higher than normal interest rates on 
large deposits.  Ordinarily, doing  this would scare people 
away.  They would assume you were paying higher than 
normal interest rates because you were in trouble, and 
hence other depositors were demanding a risk premium.  
But in this case people aren't scared away, because the 
deposits are federally insured.  The federal insurance takes 
away the market discipline.  Money fund managers 
spreading deposits nationwide will gladly accept the 
higher interest rates:  they don't have to worry about credit 
risk.  

	Then, with the new money in hand, you can 
engage in risky investments or speculations.  Anything 
that might give you a chance of making up your deficit, or 
making a windfall, before the auditors show up.  If the 
gamble succeeds, you walk away a winner.  If the value of 
your assets rises above the value of your liabilities, your 
call option is "in the money"-it pays off.  But if your 
gamble doesn't succeed, you are no worse off than before: 
Your call option expires out of the money, and your S&L 
is still broke.  The deficits on your balance sheet are 
passed along to the FSLIC.  Such was one of the many 
games played during the remainder of the 1980s.  

	The key to the whole scenario is, of course, the 
eagerness of government to blow taxpayer funds on banks 
and bank depositors.  The problem is not limited to the 
U.S.  It's worldwide.  According to the Bank for 
International Settlements:

		"Sovereign borrowers and 
		private lenders must 
		understand that incautious 
		behaviour on their part will 
		not necessarily be made 
		good with public money." 
		(*Annual Report*, Basle, 
		1996)

	But the Elysee palace and banks like Credit 
Lyonnais apparently haven't gotten the message.  Credit 
Lyonnais expects a lot more state aid.  As anticipated in 
"Credit Lyonnais and L.F. Rothschild Ready to Topple," 
the bank announced a small profit--of  French franc 67 
million (FF 67 million) for the past six months.  This 
"profit" was obtained after the bank received FF 3.9 
billion in taxpayer funds from the French government.  
Translation:  Credit Lyonnais had a FF 3.833 billion loss 
in the past six months.
	
	Credit Lyonnais also said it would need "an 
injection of at least $1.54 billion to $1.74 billion" to meet 
the government's goal of privatization (Washington Post, 
Oct. 5, 1996).  What does this mean?  Well, it means the 
French government wants to get rid of this bottomless pit, 
and sell it to private investors.  But investors are not about 
to buy something that has a negative net worth.  (Would 
you pay someone fifty dollars to take over their $1000 
debt obligation?)  So the government will have to add 
capital to the bank to give it at least a zero net worth.  And 
the bank is saying that $1.54 billion to $1.74 billion will 
do the job.  This is somewhat smaller than the $2 billion 
in the red I reported in my previous post on the subject.  
But I am confident that my numbers are at least as 
accurate as theirs.

	The French newspaper *Liberation* asked "Should 
this Bank Be Saved?", and estimated the total taxpayer 
cost of past and future bailouts to come to about $29 
billion.  This is includes about $17 billion in losses that 
will eventually materialize from the transfer of bad loans 
to the Consortium des Realisations.  

	Credit Lyonnais has had a long free ride.  It took 
in loads of money laundering deposits from the Cali cartel 
and other sources.  Then its managers invested in risky, 
prestige projects like MGM and the Chunnel project (the 
tunnel between England and France under the English 
channel).

	Credit Lyonnais used to be one of the largest 
banks in the world, based on assets.  Based on capital, its 
negative net worth of about $2 billion now makes it one 
of the world's smallest.  (Nine of the world's top ten 
banks, based on reported assets, are Japanese.  The other 
one is a German bank, Deutsche, which has about $500 
billion in assets, and ranks 7th.)

	Credit Lyonnais is now a Zombie.  It only comes 
out at night, wearing dark glasses to protect its delicate 
eyes from muted street lights, in search of other people's 
money and the neighborhood Roulette table. 

October 9, 1996
Web Page:  http://www.aci.net/kalliste/